Jean Monnet Center at NYU School of Law



Previous|Title|Next

I. Introduction

Since the 1970s, international environmental problems have become prominent issues. In order to deal with these problems, the international community has adopted numerous international agreements and some countries have legislated a variety of laws and regulations. As one of the methods for protecting international environments, some of these domestic statutes and international treaties provide trade-restrictive measures. The Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora (CITES), for instance, requires its signatories to limit trade in species that are threatened with extinction under Article III, IV, and V of the Convention.1

The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), since its establishment in the 1940s, had emphasized the significance of free trade and the lowering of tariff and non-tariff barriers.2 The GATT and its contracting parties had paid little attention to environmental problems in their discussions until the beginning of the 1990s. Environmental protection and free trade had been discussed separately and few had pointed out the possibility that their interests might come into conflict with each other.3

However, this innocence stopped abruptly when the GATT Dispute Settlement Panel found that an embargo of the United States on tuna imports based on the U.S. Marine Mammal Protection Act (MMPA) was inconsistent with the GATT.4 The MMPA includes provisions which prohibit the imports of tuna which is captured with fishing methods which result in the incidental death of marine mammals.5 The Panel found that the U.S. import ban violated GATT provisions such as Article III, which establishes the national treatment obligation, and Article XI, which prohibits quantitative import restrictions.

This finding provoked public anti-trade sentiment. Environmentalists were outraged by this Panel ruling and began to argue that the promotion of free trade undermines environmental protection. This suspicion by environmentalists was a setback for the GATT, which was, at that time, conducting the Uruguay Round of negotiations, the most complicated and largest trade liberalization negotiation in its history. Some trade experts expressed hostility towards the environmentalists' idea that some trade restrictions should be permitted in order to preserve the environment.6

Another dispute involving the MMPA arose in 1994. The European Community (EC) and the Netherlands brought complaints jointly when it became clear that Mexico, the complainant in Tuna/Dolphin I, would not push for the adoption of the Tuna/Dolphin I Panel report in the GATT because of ongoing NAFTA negotiations. The EC focused on the MMPA's "second embargo", which prohibited the imports of tuna into the U.S. from countries engaging in tuna trade with embargoed countries such as Mexico. Once again, the Panel found that the U.S. measure was inconsistent with GATT.7

In both Tuna/Dolphin I and Tuna/Dolphin II, the U.S. invoked GATT Article XX, which permits several exceptions from the GATT obligations based on such social reasons as environmental protection and preservation of public morality. In particular, the U.S. argued that its measures could be justified because they fall into the scope of Article XX (b), measures "necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health", and XX(g), measures "relating to the conservation of exhaustible natural resources".8 In Tuna/Dolphin I, after pointing out that Article XX should be construed narrowly and that the burden of proof should be placed on the party invoking it, the Panel stated that the scope of Article XX is limited to measures taken to conserve the environment within the jurisdiction of the party invoking them.9 As a result, the Panel found that the U.S. measure which aimed at protecting dolphins living outside of U.S. jurisdiction could not be justified under Article XX of the GATT.10 The Panel in Tuna/Dolphin II rejected the geographical limitation which the Tuna/Dolphin I Panel adopted.11 However, the Panel found that the U.S. measure in question was effective only when the embargoed countries changed their conservation policies and that such a measure could not be permitted under Article XX because otherwise "the balance of rights and obligations among contracting parties, in particular the right of access to markets, would be seriously impaired."12 That is, both Panels interpreted Article XX so narrowly that almost no environment-related trade measures which violate the provisions of the GATT can be justified under Article XX at all. Some point out that both Panels viewed the promotion of free trade as the preeminent value and overlooked the importance of non-trade values such as environment protection.13

However, since the establishment of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1995, the interpretation of Article XX has been loosened. The Appellate Body (AB), which is a permanent dispute settlement body in the WTO to review Panel decisions, adopted balancing approaches in the cases involving environment-related trade measures such as United States - Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline (hereinafter Gasoline)14 and United States - Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products (hereinafter Shrimp/Turtle).15 In these cases, the AB paid attention to balancing the promotion of free trade with environmental protection when interpreting GATT Article XX. One of the reasons why the AB discarded the Panels' approaches in Tuna/Dolphin I and II vis-à-vis GATT Article XX is the change in the preamble of the WTO Agreement16 from that of GATT 1947.17 As opposed to the GATT 1947, the preamble of the WTO Agreement acknowledges the importance of environmental protection. It provides that a purpose of the WTO is to accomplish "the optimal use of the world's resources in accordance with the objective of sustainable development, seeking both to protect and preserve the environment and to enhance the means for doing so in a manner consistent with their respective needs and concerns at different levels of economic development".18 As a matter of fact, in Shrimp/Turtle, the AB interpreted the term of Article XX (g) in the light of the preamble of the WTO Agreement.19

These discussions regarding the relationship between trade and environmental policies can be "economized". From a viewpoint of economic theory, environment-oriented trade measures (ETMs)20 could be justified based on the existence of externalities or common property goods.21 As a matter of general proposition, externalities arise when the economic activities of economic entities such as consumers and producers cause effects which are not directly reflected in the market. Externalities can be either negative, such as when the activity of a party impose costs on another party, or positive, when the action of a party benefits another party. When negative (positive) externalities arise, the amount of the activity which causes the externalities would be excessive (less than optimal) since the actor does not take into account the costs (benefits) of the other party. In the context of international trade, negative externalities occur when a state exports products which inflict detrimental effects on the importing state's nationals. These negative externalities would be "internalized" by restricting or controlling the imports of the products. However, there is vigorous debate as to what extent the WTO should permit externalities as a justification for ETMs since 1) ETMs are not the only method for "internalizing" externalities and 2) externalities are very difficult to define.22 Common property goods are those to which everyone has free access. As a result, they tend to be overutilized since, when economic entities use common property goods, they do not take into account how their use would affect the opportunities of others. In the context of international trade, the preservation of the global environmental commons would be the most significant issue; global commons are defined as "physical or biological systems that lie wholly or largely outside the jurisdiction of any of the individual members of society but that are valued resources for many members of society"23. For example, atmosphere, the ozone layer, and endangered species can fall within the category of the global environmental commons. It would be possible to deal with the problems of overutilizing the global environmental commons by invoking ETMs. For example, in Shrimp/Turtle, the U.S. tried to preserve seven kinds of sea turtles, which are listed in Appendix 1 of CITES, by banning the imports of shrimps from those countries which did not adopt regulatory programs comparable to those of the U.S. in order to prevent the incidental capture of sea turtles by shrimp trawlers. This U.S. measure can be regarded as an ETM aimed at dealing with problems concerning the overutilization of a common environmental good. Once again, it is also hotly discussed to what extent ETMs for preventing the overuse of the global environmental commons should be allowed under the WTO.

Many have discussed whether the use of ETMs should be allowed under the WTO from an economic viewpoint.24 Some argue that trade restriction is not usually an appropriate method for dealing with environmental problems,25 and others refute their opinions.26 However, the primary concerns in these discussions are limited to only two types of ETMs: ETMs which aim at coercing the countries targeted by the ETMs to improve their environmental behavior beyond the jurisdiction of the ETM-invoking countries; and ETMs which try to compensate for the targeted nations' less strict environmental regulations by imposing tax or countervailing duties.27 These two kinds of ETMs do not represent all environmental measures which would affect international trade. States invoke environmental measures which aim at protecting the safety of nationals or the environment regardless of purporting to change other countries' environmental policies. For example, states prohibit the production and consumption of certain kinds of products which bring about risks to human health. In order to render these prohibition effective, states also ban the imports of these products. Even though these environmental measures do not intend to change environmental policies of other states, they would also cause pernicious effects on international trade. As a matter of fact, this kind of ETM became the issue in the most of the disputes that have been involved in "trade and environment" since the establishment of the WTO. For instance, in European Communities - Measures Affecting Asbestos and Asbestos -Containing Products, Canada complained about the French import ban of asbestos, a measure which was an aspect of France's general prohibition of the sale, use, and manufacture of asbestos in France.28 Although this French measure does not purport to change the Canadian environmental policy, it causes harmful effects on the Canadian export of asbestos. Also included in this category of ETM are most of the sanitary and technical measures which fall under the scope of the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (hereinafter the TBT Agreement)29 and the Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (the SPS Agreement).30 These agreements came into force when the WTO was established and aim at preventing technical regulations and sanitary measures of the members from "creat[ing] unnecessary obstacles to international trade".31 Even though these agreements attempt to "minimize... the negative effects [of sanitary and technical regulations] on trade"32, it is crystal clear that they do not intend to deprive the sovereign right of the WTO members to enact sanitary and technical regulations in order to protect human health. Therefore, when we analyze this type of ETM (i.e., measures aimed at preserving the environment without intending to change other countries' environmental policies), it does not make sense to discuss whether this kind of ETM should be allowed under the WTO. Rather, the concern of this paper is that ETM-imposing countries tend to choose measures which impose a heavy burden on international trade because they do not have an incentive to take into account the trade harms on other countries. This paper will primarily discuss whether the judicial tests which have been adopted by the Appellate Body and Panel (hereinafter the AB&P) in the WTO in the analysis of the SPS Agreement, the TBT Agreement, and GATT Article XX33, for example, the "least trade restrictive alternative" test and the "means and ends" test, could appropriately "correct" the behavior of ETM-imposing countries so as to achieve the "optimal use of the world's resources."

In analyzing these "judicial" tests, we are going to take into account two additional issues: the application/measure dichotomy, and the allocation of the burden of proof. In the analysis of GATT Article XX, the AB&P have adopted the dichotomy between the essence and the application of a measure. This distinction would have certain effects to render the AB&P's scrutiny more deferential to ETMs. The allocation of the burden of proof would also have significant effects in determining how moderate or stringent the AB&P's analysis on ETMs is. For example, their analysis would be more deferential to ETMs if they impose the burden of proving the unjustifiablity of the ETMs under GATT Article XX on complaining countries and vice versa.

This paper will begin with a discussion in Chapter II regarding the findings in the WTO cases involving the SPS Agreement, the TBT Agreement, and GATT Article XX. Chapter III will analyze above-mentioned judicial tests such as "least trade restrictive alternative" test and the "means and ends" test from an economic viewpoint. Chapter IV will examine the essence/application dichotomy which the AB&P have adopted. Chapter V will discuss the allocation of the burden of proof in the contexts of GATT Article XX and the SPS Agreement. Chapter VI will conclude.


1 Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora, Mar. 3, 197, 27 U.S.T. 1087, 993 U.N.T.S. 243 [hereinafter CITES].

2 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Oct 30, 1947 T.I.A.S. No. 1700, 55 U.N.T.S. 194 [hereinafter GATT 1947].

3 See HAKAN NORDSTROM & SCOTT VAUGHAN, TRADE AND ENVIRONMENT 8 (WTO Special Studies 4, 1999) (stating that "trade was not perceived to be an environmental issue as such, neither among policy makers nor the public at large").

4 See GATT Dispute Settlement Panel Report: United States- Restriction on Imports on Tuna, GATT Doc. DS21/R, August 16, 1991 (not adopted), GATT BISD (39th Supp.) 155 (1993). [hereinafter Tuna/Dolphin I]

5 See The Marine Mammal Protection Act, 16 U.S.C.§ 1371 (a) (2) (1994) [hereinafter MMPA].

6 With regard to the early history of the "trade and environment" discussion, see Daniel C. Esty, Greening the GATT: Trade, Environment and the Future (1994).

7 See GATT Dispute Settlement Panel Report: United States- Restrictions on Imports of Tuna, GATT Doc. DS 29/R, June 16, 1994, reprinted in 33 I.L.M. 839 (1994) [hereinafter Tuna/Dolphin II].

8 See Id. Para. 3.7; Tuna/Dolphin I, supra note 4, at para. 3.33, 40.

9 See Tuna/Dolphin I, supra note 4, at para. 5.31.

10 See Id. at para. 5.32.

11 See Tuna/Dolphin II, supra note 7, at para.5.15-20.

12 Id. at para. 5.26.

13 See e.g. Richard J. McLaughlin, Sovereignty, Utility, and Fairness: Using U.S. Takings Law to Guide the Evolving Utilitarian Balancing Approach to Global Environmental Disputes in the WTO, 78 OR. L. REV. 855, 872-74(1999).

14 WTO Report of the Appellate Body: United States-Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline, WT/DS2/AB/R (Apr. 29, 1996), reprinted in 35 I.L.M. 603 (1996) [hereinafter Gasoline AB Report].

15 WTO Report of the Appellate Body: United States-Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, WT/DS58/AB/R (Oct. 12, 1998), reprinted in 38 I.L.M. 118 (1999) [hereinafter Shrimp/Turtle AB Report].

16 Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Apr. 15, 1994, The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations: The Legal Texts 6 (1994).

17 McLaughlin points out that the reason why the AB introduced a new balancing approach would be: "(1) the change in the WTO dispute settlement regime from a non-binding to a binding system; (2) the establishment of a permanent appellate body with a mandate to review errors of law; and (3) consensus among the most powerful members of the WTO that international environmental protection must be recognized by the trade organization as a legitimate area of concern." See McLaughlin, supra note 13, at 890.

18 Id. at Preamble.

19 See Shrimp/Turtle AB Report, supra note 15, at para. 129-130.

20 "Trade measures" here is not limited to those in which a tax and regulation is exclusively applied to traded goods at a country's border; the application of the GATT is not limited to those measures. A "domestic" tax or a regulation which is applied to both domestic and foreign products also affect international trade by modifying the competitive relationship between the domestic and foreign products and therefore are within the scope of the GATT (for example, Article III of the GATT). These domestic measures are also within the domain of the trade measures which will be discussed in this paper. See Steve Charnovitz, Trade Measures and the Design of International Regimes, 5 J. Env't & Dev., No. 2, 168, 171(1996).

21 See e.g. HAKAN NORDSTROM & SCOTT VAUGHAN, supra note 3, at 13-27; Howard F. Chang, Trade Measures to Protect the Global Environment, 83 Geo. L.J. 2131, 2146 (1995) [hereinafter Chang 1995]; David Pearce, The Greening of the GATT: Some Economic Considerations, in Trade & Environment: The Search for Balance, Volume I, 20, 29-33 (James Cameron et al. eds. 1994),

22 See Jeffrey L. Dunoff & Joel P. Trachtman, Economic Analysis of International Law, 24 Yale. J. Int'l Law 1, 15 (1999).

23 G. Hardin, The Tragedy of the Commons, in Managing The Commons (San Francisco: W.H. Freeman, 1977).

24 See e.g. Chang 1995, supra note 21; Howard F. Chang. Carrots, Sticks, and International Externalities, 17 Int'l Rev. L & Econ 309 (1997) [hereinafter Chang 1997]; Robert Howse & Michael J. Trebilcock, The Fair Trade-Free Trade Debate: Trade, Labor, and the Environment, 16 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ 61. (1996); McLaughlin, supra note 13; Pearce, supra note 21 (arguing that, even though the GATT seems to distinguish the externalities derived from the consumption of a product in the importing countries, for example the risk arising from the use of imported asbestos, from the externalities derived from the production of a product in the exporting countries, for example the harvest of shrimps by turtle-unsafe methods, by scrutinizing the latter more stringently than the former, there is no economic justification for this distinction.); Arvind Subramanian, Trade Measures for Environment: A Nearly Empty Box?, World Econ., Jan. 1992, 135.

25 See e.g. Subramanian, supra note 24 (arguing that, "in relation to domestic environmental problems, the use of trade measures is flawed because it is largely protectionist in intent... [I]n relation to transboundary environmental problems,... trade interventions were inefficient instruments in correcting the market failures creating the environmental problem"[emphasis in original]).

26 See e.g. Chang 1995, supra note 21; Chang 1997, supra note 24 (arguing that the use of "sticks", i.e. trade measures, is more likely to enhance global economic welfare than the "carrot only" approach, i.e. subsidy).

27 See e.g. John Whalley, The Interface between Environmental and Trade Policies, 101 Econ. J. 180, 186-88 (1991).

28 WTO Report of the Panel: European Communities -Measures Affecting Asbestos and Asbestos-Containing Products, WT/DS135/R (Sep. 18, 2000), available at <http://www.wto.org> (last visited Mar. 15, 2001) [hereinafter Asbestos Panel Report]; WTO Report of the Appellate Body: European Communities -Measures Affecting Asbestos and Asbestos-Containing Products, WT/DS135/AB/R (Mar. 12, 2001), available at <http://www.wto.org> (last visited Mar. 15, 2001) [hereinafter Asbestos AB Report].

29 Agreement on the Technical Barriers to Trade, Apr. 15, 1994, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Annex 1A, World Trade Organization, The Legal Texts: The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations 163 (1999) [hereinafter the TBT Agreement].

30 Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures, Apr. 15, 1994, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Annex 1A, World Trade Organization, The Legal Texts: The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations 59 (1999) [hereinafter the SPS Agreement].

31 The TBT Agreement, supra note 29, at preamble.

32 The SPS Agreement, supra note 30, at preamble.

33 In the discussion concerning "trade and environment" in the context of the GATT, GATT Article XX is not the only relevant provision. For example, environment-oriented measures which affect international trade would be deemed to be consistent with GATT Article III. In Asbestos, the AB found that a French decree which prohibited the use, manufacture, sale, and import of asbestos and asbestos-containing products was not inconsistent with GATT Article III, reversing the Panel's findings that chrysotile asbestos fibres and PCG fibres, non-asbestos fibres some of whose end-uses are similar to those of chrysotile asbestos fibres, were like products. See Asbestos AB Report, supra note 28. Furthermore, the AB noted that "even if two products are `like', that does not mean that a measure is inconsistent with Article III:4. A complaining Member must still establish that the measure accords to the group of "like" imported products `less favourable treatment' than it accords to the group of `like' domestic products"[emphasis in original]. Id. at para. 100. With regard to the implication that the use of the word "group" might have, see infra note 103. Therefore, it is possible that environmental regulations designed to "internalize" the externalities derived from environmental problems does not have to be scrutinized by the judicial tests invoked under GATT Article XX. However, this paper limits the scope of the discussion to Article XX except for a few occasional references to GATT Article III; if we want to expand our discussion to GATT Article III, we need to conduct a careful analysis of the Article III non-discrimination principle, and such an analysis is too involved an issue to be treated here in detail.

Top|Previous|Title|Next

 

 


This site is part of the Academy of European Law online, a joint partnership of the Jean Monnet Center at NYU School of Law and the Academy of European Law at the European University Institute.
Questions or comments about this site?
Email Enfellows@exchange.law.nyu.edu